Parenthood and Risk Preferences

Transcription

Parenthood and Risk Preferences
RUHR
ECONOMIC PAPERS
Katja Görlitz
Marcus Tamm
Parenthood and Risk Preferences
#552
Imprint
Ruhr Economic Papers
Published by
Ruhr-Universität Bochum (RUB), Department of Economics
Universitätsstr. 150, 44801 Bochum, Germany
Technische Universität Dortmund, Department of Economic and Social Sciences
Vogelpothsweg 87, 44227 Dortmund, Germany
Universität Duisburg-Essen, Department of Economics
Universitätsstr. 12, 45117 Essen, Germany
Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (RWI)
Hohenzollernstr. 1-3, 45128 Essen, Germany
Editors
Prof. Dr. Thomas K. Bauer
RUB, Department of Economics, Empirical Economics
Phone: +49 (0) 234/3 22 83 41, e-mail: [email protected]
Prof. Dr. Wolfgang Leininger
Technische Universität Dortmund, Department of Economic and Social Sciences
Economics – Microeconomics
Phone: +49 (0) 231/7 55-3297, e-mail: [email protected]
Prof. Dr. Volker Clausen
University of Duisburg-Essen, Department of Economics
International Economics
Phone: +49 (0) 201/1 83-3655, e-mail: [email protected]
Prof. Dr. Roland Döhrn, Prof. Dr. Manuel Frondel, Prof. Dr. Jochen Kluve
RWI, Phone: +49 (0) 201/81 49 -213, e-mail: [email protected]
Editorial Office
Sabine Weiler
RWI, Phone: +49 (0) 201/81 49 -213, e-mail: [email protected]
Ruhr Economic Papers #552
Responsible Editor: Jochen Kluve
All rights reserved. Bochum, Dortmund, Duisburg, Essen, Germany, 2015
ISSN 1864-4872 (online) – ISBN 978-3-86788-630-7
The working papers published in the Series constitute work in progress circulated to
stimulate discussion and critical comments. Views expressed represent exclusively the
authors’ own opinions and do not necessarily reflect those of the editors.
Ruhr Economic Papers #552
Katja Görlitz and Marcus Tamm
Parenthood and Risk Preferences
Bibliografische Informationen
der Deutschen Nationalbibliothek
Die Deutsche Bibliothek verzeichnet diese Publikation in der deutschen Nationalbibliografie; detaillierte bibliografische Daten sind im Internet über:
http://dnb.d-nb.de abrufbar.
Das RWI wird vom Bund und vom Land Nordrhein-Westfalen gefördert.
http://dx.doi.org/10.4419/86788630
ISSN 1864-4872 (online)
ISBN 978-3-86788-630-7
Katja Görlitz and Marcus Tamm1
Parenthood and Risk Preferences
Abstract
This study analyzes how risk attitudes change when individuals become parents using
longitudinal data for a large and representative sample of individuals. The results
show that men and women experience a considerable increase in risk aversion which
already starts as early as two years before becoming a parent, is largest shortly after
giving birth and disappears when the child becomes older. These findings show that
parenthood leads to considerable changes in individual risk attitudes over time. Thus,
analyses using risk preferences as the explanatory variable for economic outcomes
should be careful in interpreting the findings as causal effects.
JEL Classification: D1, D81, J13, J16
Keywords: Risk aversion; risk preferences; preference stability; parenthood; children;
gender differences
April 2015
1 Katja Görlitz, FU Berlin, RWI, and IZA; Marcus Tamm, RWI and IZA. – We acknowledge helpful comments and suggestions by
Frank Fossen and Stefanie Schurer. – All correspondence to: Marcus Tamm, RWI - Büro Berlin, Invalidenstr. 112, 10115 Berlin,
Germany, e-mail: [email protected]
1. Introduction
Risk preferences are important determinants for almost every economically relevant
decision of individuals such as financial investments, consumption, employment and
occupational choice. While standard economic models assume risk preferences to be stable
over time, the empirical literature has found that they do change as a consequence of negative
macro shocks such as natural disasters (Hanaoka et al. 2014, Eckel et al. 2009), civil conflicts
(Voors et al. 2012) or financial crises (Guiso et al. 2013). Yet, little is known about the impact
of individual-specific life events on preferences. One exception is Sahm (2012) who sheds
light on the importance of job displacements and serious health diagnoses. In this paper, we
analyze the family-related event of becoming a parent. While some authors have assumed that
parenthood increases risk aversion (e.g. DeLeire and Levy 2004), to our knowledge, we are
the first to show this empirically.
The analysis is based on representative longitudinal household data containing information
on individuals’ general risk attitudes in seven panel waves in addition to demographic and
family-related information. Applying individual fixed-effects regressions, we investigate
whether individuals’ risk attitudes change as a consequence of parenthood and (if so) whether
it is a permanent change or a transitory one that fades away when children grow old.
This paper contributes to the empirical literature that is concerned with identifying the
extent to which risk preferences predict individuals’ behavior, for example, with respect to
health-related behavior, financial investments (Barsky et al. 1997, Dohmen et al. 2011),
occupational choice (Bonin et al. 2007, Caliendo et al. 2009), marriage and childbearing
(Schmidt 2008). If risk preferences change as a result of life events that are themselves
correlated with the behavioral outcomes of interest, a regression of outcomes on risk
preferences without accounting for their endogeneity would produce biased estimates.
Parenthood is likely to be correlated with a variety of individual choices which makes this
aspect important for a wide range of applications.
Furthermore, due to the different roles of men and women in parenthood, e.g., in giving
birth and raising children, we test whether the impact of parenthood on risk attitudes differs
by gender. This contributes to the literature concerned with explaining gender differences in
economic choices. It could also help to explain the stylized fact that women appear to be more
risk averse than men (e.g. Eckel and Grossman 2008). If risk aversion of women reacted more
sensitive after childbirth than that of men, this could explain some of the gender gap in risk
aversion.
4
2. Data
The analysis relies on data from the German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP), a
representative longitudinal survey of private households in Germany.1 SOEP includes a
question on general risk attitudes in 2004, 2006 and from 2008 to 2012, leaving us a total of
seven panel waves of data. The general risk attitude is measured by a survey question on
individuals’ self-assessed willingness to take risks. The English translation of the risk
question reads: “How do you see yourself: Are you generally a person who is willing to take
risks or do you try to avoid risks? Please answer on a scale from 0 to 10, where 0 means ‘not
at all willing to take risks’ and 10 means ‘very willing to take risks’.” Dohmen et al. (2011)
show, also using the SOEP data, that this question is behavioral valid and a reliable predictor
of actual risk-taking behavior in a paid lottery-type experiment.
The estmation sample is restricted to individuals aged 17 to 64. It covers 29,000
individuals and 107,000 person-year observations. There is hardly any item nonresponse in
the question of risk attitudes (0.4 percent) and in the other variables used in the empirical
analysis. On average, each individual reports information on his or her risk attitude in three to
four panel waves. 6,700 individuals answer the question on risk attitudes in seven waves,
3,000 individuals in six waves and 1,800 in five waves. Taken together these individuals who
answer the risk question at least five times account for almost 70 percent of all person-year
observations. Within the time period under consideration 1,243 respondents experienced the
birth of their first child. This provides ample opportunities to observe individual changes in
risk attitudes and parental status over time.
Table 1 displays the summary statistics on the willingness to take risks by gender and
parental status. The average risk attitude is 4.68, with women reporting a lower willingness to
take risks (4.27) than men (5.14). For both genders alike, childless individuals have a higher
risk attitude than parents. When splitting the sample further by years since birth of the first
child, risk aversion varies a lot for both genders in a non-systematic way. However, since the
descriptive statistics do not account for parents’ age that has been shown to correlate with risk
aversion (Schurer 2015), a final conclusion can only be drawn from regression results.
1
The data has been extracted using the Stata add-on-package PanelWhiz v4.0 (Oct 2012). HaiskenDeNew and Hahn (2010) document PanelWhiz.
5
Table 1 – Summary statistics of individuals’ risk attitudes
Women
Mean
SD
All
4.27
2.21
Without children
4.67
2.19
With children
4.08
2.20
By years since birth of first child
< 1 year
4.12
2.11
1-3 years
4.33
2.15
4-6 years
4.28
2.14
7-9 years
4.13
2.17
10-18 years
4.16
2.17
> 18 years
3.99
2.22
Observations
56,023
Men
Mean
SD
5.14
2.21
5.33
2.21
4.98
2.20
All
Mean
4.68
5.04
4.46
5.19
2.16
5.25
2.10
5.19
2.13
5.17
2.19
5.10
2.18
4.83
2.23
51,061
4.61
2.20
4.76
2.17
4.70
2.18
4.61
2.24
4.60
2.22
4.33
2.26
107,084
SD
2.26
2.23
2.25
3. Estimation and results
The aim of the regression analysis is to show how parenthood changes individuals’
willingness to take risks. The following regression model is estimated:
‫ݕ‬௜௧ ൌ ‫ܤ‬௜௧ Ԣߚ ൅ ܺ௜௧ ᇱ ߜ ൅ ߙ௜ ൅ ߝ௜௧
where y is the risk attitude of individual i at time t (with t=2004, 2006, 2008-2012). The
vector B comprises dummy variables that indicate the time after the birth of the first child: the
first year after childbirth (b0) and for each following year up to when the child is aged 6 (b1 to
b6). From 6 years after childbirth onwards, the following group dummies are defined: 7 to 9
years, 10 to 12 years, 13 to 15 years, 16 to 18 years and 19 years and above. To look at
changes in risk attitudes up to three years before childbirth, we also include the three dummy
variables b-3 to b-1. Any changes before childbirth might indicate that individuals first settle
down before becoming parents and that settling down already influences risk preferences. The
vector of control variables X comprises age in a cubic specification, year dummies and a
binary indicator for the birth of a second child. The latter enables us distinguishing the effect
of becoming a parent (by having a first child) from the effect of a subsequent birth. The
coefficient ߙ௜ comprises individual fixed-effects.
The regression is estimated by applying the linear fixed-effects model. Furthermore, we
apply the following three fixed-effects models that take the ordinal nature of the dependent
variable into account: the “blow-up and cluster” (BUC) estimator (Baetschmann et al. 2014),
the two-step minimum estimator (Das and van Soest 1999), henceforth DvS, and the estimator
suggested by Ferrer-i-Carbonell and Frijters (2004), henceforth FCF.
6
The regression results are presented in Table 2. Since the results from the linear fixedeffects model (Table 2, columns 1 and 5) are basically the same as those from the other
models (Table 2, columns 2 to 4 and 6 to 8), the following discussion concentrates on the
linear fixed-effects results. For illustrative purposes, Figure 1 depicts the point estimates
(solid lines) together with the 90% confidence interval (dashed lines). It can be seen that both
women’s and men’s risk attitude is significantly lower after the birth of the first child and that
both become more risk averse as early as two years before the birth of the first child.2
For women, Table 2 shows that the size of the decrease in risk attitudes is 0.6 points in the
year after the first child was born.3 This is equivalent to a drop by more than a fourth of a
standard deviation. Between b1 and b7-9, the effects are still significantly negative ranging
from െ0.35 to െ0.53 points. Afterwards, risk attitudes rise continuously and 12 years after the
birth of the first child the effect becomes statistically insignificant. Men also become more
risk averse around the birth of the first child, but the point estimate is somewhat smaller for
them (െ0.36 points in b0). The level of risk attitudes is lowest in the year when the child is
one year old (െ0.42 points) which is equivalent to a decrease by a fifth of a standard
deviation. Five years after childbirth, the effects for men cannot be rejected to differ from zero
on a significance level of 10 percent.4 Figure 1 suggests that the overall pattern of how risk
attitudes change as a consequence of parenthood is somewhat flatter for men than for women.
However, this suggestion is not supported by statistical tests: There are neither significant
gender differences when testing each birth-related coefficient against one another nor are they
significant when running a joint test of equality of all gender-specific birth-related
coefficients. For the interpretation of the results, note that the impact of having a second child
is insignificant which indicates that becoming a parent for the first time changes risk attitudes
and not the birth of a second child.
2
The effects before childbirth do not appear to be driven by marriage. In specifications controlling for
marriage or for marital status the results remain unchanged for the birth-related coefficients and the
marriage dummy is always insignificant.
3
Also note that for women the effect in b0 differs significantly from the effect in b-1 (p-value 0.0157).
4
When using the 5 percent significance level, this would be the case three years after childbirth. Also,
fewer of the point estimates for men would be considered to differ from zero. In contrast, for women
conclusions are the same irrespective of using the 5 or 10 percent significance level.
7
.5
.5
Figure 1 – Birth of the first child and the evolution of risk attitudes by gender
-.5
0
Men
-1
-1
-.5
0
Women
-2
0
2
4
6
7 to 9
10 to 12 13 to 15 16 to 18
>18
-2
Years since birth of 1st child
0
2
4
6
7 to 9
10 to 12 13 to 15 16 to 18
>18
Years since birth of 1st child
Note: The figures display the estimated regression coefficients (solid lines) together with the 90%
confidence intervals (dashed lines) from the linear fixed-effects models presented in Table 2.
4. Conclusion
The results show that risk attitudes are not stable across time. Both men and women
become more risk averse after the birth of their first child. This change of risk attitudes starts
as early as two years before giving birth and is most pronounced shortly after the birth of the
first child. The effect becomes smaller and statistically insignificant when the child grows
older. Overall, we find clear evidence that family-related events can change individual risk
attitudes. Therefore, in empirical applications that analyze how risk preferences predict
individual decision making, risk attitudes cannot be treated as exogenous. Another finding is
that the relationship between time since childbirth and risk attitudes does not differ
significantly by gender. Thus, we conclude that the consequences of parenthood do not
contribute to explaining the empirical finding of a gender gap in risk attitudes.
References
Barsky, Robert, Thomas Juster, Miles Kimball and Matthew Shapiro (1997), Preference
Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and
Retirement Study, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2), 537-579.
Baetschmann, Gregori, Kevin Straub and Rainer Winkelmann (2014), Consistent estimation
of the fixed effects logit model, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in
Society), doi: 10.1111/rssa.12090.
Bonin, Holger, Thomas Dohmen, Armin Falk, David Huffman and Uwe Sunde (2007), Crosssectional earnings risk and occupational sorting: The role of risk attitudes, Labour Economics
14(6), 926-937.
8
Caliendo, Marco, Frank Fossen and Alexander Kritikos (2009): Risk Attitudes of Nascent
Entrepreneurs - New Evidence from an Experimentally-Validated Survey, Small Business
Economics, 32(2), 153-167.
Das, Marcel and Arthur van Soest (1999), A panel data model for subjective information on
household income growth, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 40(4), 409-426.
DeLeire, Thomas and Helen Levy (2004), Worker Sorting and the Risk of Death on the Job,
Journal of Labor Economics 22(4), 925-953.
Dohmen, Thomas, Armin Falk, David Huffman, Uwe Sunde, Jürgen Schupp and Gert Wagner
(2011), Individual Risk Attitudes: Measurement, Determinants and Behavioral Consequences,
Journal of the European Economic Association 9(3), 522-550.
Eckel, Catherine, Mahmoud El Gamalb and Rick Wilson (2009), Risk Loving After the
Storm: A Bayesian-Network Study of Hurricane Katrina Evacuees, Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization 69(2), 110-124.
Eckel, Catherine and Philip Grossman (2008), Men, Women and Risk Aversion:
Experimental Evidence. In: Plott, Charles and Vernon Smith (eds.), Handbook of
Experimental Economics, Vol. 1, 1061-1073. Amsterdam et al.: Elsevier.
Ferrer-i-Carbonell, Ada and Paul Frijters (2004), How important is methodology for the
estimates of the determinants of happiness? The Economic Journal 114(497), 641-659.
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza and Luigi Zingales (2013), Time varying risk aversion, NBER
working paper 19284.
Haisken-DeNew, John and Markus Hahn (2010), PanelWhiz: Efficient Data Extraction of
Complex Panel Data Sets – An Example Using the German SOEP, Journal of Applied Social
Science Studies 130(4), 643-654.
Hanaoka, Chie, Hitoshi Shigeoka and Yasutora Watanabe (2014), Do Risk Preferences
Change? Evidence from Panel Data before and after the Great East Japan Earthquake.
Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2425396.
Sahm, Claudia (2012), How Much does Risk Tolerance Change? Quarterly Journal of Finance
2(4), 1250020.
Schmidt, Lucie (2008), Risk Preferences and the Timing of Marriage and Childbearing,
Demography 45(2), 439-460.
Schurer, Stefanie (2015), Lifecycle Patterns in the Socioeconomic Gradient of Risk
Preferences, IZA discussion paper 8821.
Voors, Maarten, Eleonora Nillesen, Philip Verwimp, Erwin Bulte, Robert Lensink and Daan
van Soest (2012), Does Conflict Affect Preferences? Results from Field Experiments in
Burundi, American Economic Review 102(2), 941-964.
9
BUC
(2)
-0.1309
(0.1815)
-0.3131**
(0.1539)
-0.4371***
(0.1610)
-0.7790***
(0.1544)
-0.5389***
(0.1644)
-0.5684***
(0.1724)
-0.5828***
(0.1834)
-0.5617***
(0.1895)
-0.6631***
(0.1972)
-0.4439**
(0.2023)
-0.5704***
(0.2071)
-0.4826**
(0.2242)
-0.3178
(0.2408)
-0.1348
(0.2553)
-0.0958
(0.2721)
0.1218
(0.1046)
yes
183,116
DvS
(3)
-0.1072
(0.1666)
-0.2080
(0.1457)
-0.4204***
(0.1495)
-0.7081***
(0.1462)
-0.4928***
(0.1554)
-0.5049***
(0.1620)
-0.5671***
(0.1735)
-0.5018***
(0.1791)
-0.6085***
(0.1884)
-0.4093**
(0.1927)
-0.5321***
(0.1976)
-0.4035*
(0.2147)
-0.2268
(0.2316)
-0.0573
(0.2460)
-0.0177
(0.2626)
0.1416
(0.0969)
yes
49,978
FCF
(4)
-0.0990
(0.1703)
-0.2763*
(0.1519)
-0.4773***
(0.1574)
-0.6884***
(0.1463)
-0.4251***
(0.1605)
-0.4919***
(0.1675)
-0.4871***
(0.1735)
-0.4589**
(0.1843)
-0.6098***
(0.1935)
-0.3535*
(0.1972)
-0.4833**
(0.1992)
-0.3854*
(0.2163)
-0.3297
(0.2318)
-0.1480
(0.2464)
-0.1521
(0.2627)
0.0656
(0.1034)
yes
49,978
Men
Linear FE
(5)
-0.1501
(0.1458)
-0.3204**
(0.1321)
-0.2393*
(0.1249)
-0.3623***
(0.1246)
-0.4226***
(0.1263)
-0.2487*
(0.1345)
-0.3678**
(0.1439)
-0.2521*
(0.1527)
-0.3000*
(0.1605)
-0.2480
(0.1643)
-0.2718
(0.1680)
-0.2903
(0.1832)
-0.1820
(0.1955)
-0.1801
(0.2088)
-0.1636
(0.2221)
0.0036
(0.0934)
yes
51,061
BUC
(6)
-0.2391
(0.1960)
-0.4842***
(0.1750)
-0.3461**
(0.1722)
-0.5220***
(0.1672)
-0.5646***
(0.1709)
-0.3818**
(0.1795)
-0.5115***
(0.1891)
-0.3893*
(0.1990)
-0.4356**
(0.2089)
-0.3563*
(0.2140)
-0.3990*
(0.2181)
-0.4214*
(0.2374)
-0.2709
(0.2530)
-0.2630
(0.2684)
-0.2423
(0.2844)
0.0118
(0.1156)
yes
161,716
DvS
(7)
-0.0732
(0.1738)
-0.5404***
(0.1589)
-0.2905*
(0.1540)
-0.4263***
(0.1473)
-0.4783***
(0.1555)
-0.3007*
(0.1619)
-0.5166***
(0.1725)
-0.3522*
(0.1797)
-0.4413**
(0.1914)
-0.3104
(0.1970)
-0.3680*
(0.2017)
-0.3944*
(0.2211)
-0.2321
(0.2365)
-0.2225
(0.2523)
-0.1844
(0.2684)
0.1026
(0.1105)
yes
45,272
FCF
(8)
-0.2702
(0.1908)
-0.4588***
(0.1691)
-0.2365
(0.1709)
-0.4126**
(0.1649)
-0.5865***
(0.1703)
-0.4616***
(0.1742)
-0.4674**
(0.1844)
-0.4525**
(0.1962)
-0.4771**
(0.2009)
-0.5510***
(0.2090)
-0.4970**
(0.2130)
-0.4955**
(0.2304)
-0.4803*
(0.2464)
-0.4185
(0.2617)
-0.4341
(0.2779)
0.1738
(0.1104)
yes
45,272
10
Note: The dependent variable is the self-reported risk attitude measured on a scale from 0 (extremely risk averse) to 10 (very willing to
take risks). Estimates account for clustering at the person level.
Age and year effects
Observations
Birth of second child b•0
Birth of first child b>18
Birth of first child b16-18
Birth of first child b13-15
Birth of first child b10-12
Birth of first child b7-9
Birth of first child b6
Birth of first child b5
Birth of first child b4
Birth of first child b3
Birth of first child b2
Birth of first child b1
Birth of first child b0
Birth of first child b-1
Birth of first child b-2
Birth of first child b-3
Women
Linear FE
(1)
-0.1086
(0.1409)
-0.2542**
(0.1232)
-0.3519***
(0.1265)
-0.6042***
(0.1214)
-0.4193***
(0.1300)
-0.4324***
(0.1356)
-0.4546***
(0.1454)
-0.4414***
(0.1522)
-0.5334***
(0.1581)
-0.3512**
(0.1632)
-0.4459***
(0.1664)
-0.3755**
(0.1804)
-0.2494
(0.1941)
-0.1056
(0.2063)
-0.0762
(0.2202)
0.1106
(0.0870)
yes
56,023
Table 2 –The change of risk attitudes after becoming a parent

Documents pareils